Politics

From Citizendium
Revision as of 02:48, 9 May 2011 by imported>Nick Gardner (→‎Overview)
Jump to navigation Jump to search
This article is developed but not approved.
Main Article
Discussion
Related Articles  [?]
Bibliography  [?]
External Links  [?]
Citable Version  [?]
Timelines [?]
Addendum [?]
Index [?]
Glossary [?]
 
This editable, developed Main Article is subject to a disclaimer.

Politics is about living together in communities. As "social animals", humans have always tended to form groups, the better to enjoy the benefits of cooperation and mutual defence; and groups have merged to form tribes, city-states. empires, and nation-states. The subject-matter of politics includes relations within and between those groups, beliefs concerning the proper conduct of those relations, and systems and institutions for regulating that conduct.

Overview

The subject-matter of politics includes the consideration of such philosophical issues as the extent to which individual conduct should be made subordinate to the will of the community, and that of the proper rôle of the state as an expression of the will of the community. It also includes the consideration of such practical issues as the formulation and enforcement of rules governing the relations between the individual and the state. An understanding of how such issues have been resolved by particular communities requires an appreciation of the collective beliefs (or ideologies) that are held by members of those communities. At the operational level it concerns issues such as the conditions governing the legitimacy of government; the extent to which government decision-making should be determined by ethical considerations rather than by its intended consequences; and the consideration that should be given to the welfare of foreign nationals.

The development of political thought

Fundamentals

Freedom of choice

The fundamental political question is why an individual should submit to restraints imposed upon him by others. The philosopher Isaiah Berlin has termed such submission the relinquishment of "negative freedom" in order to achieve "positive freedom" - a submission that is analogous to the exercise of self-discipline in order to accomplish a task [1]. His answer to that question was that external restraints are accepted in order to gain the advantages of cooperation and mutual defence, and he claimed that to be the motivational basis of politics. The concept of a collective voluntary agreement for that purpose, which had been formulated by Jean-Jacques Rousseau as the Social contract, [2] was a fiction, but it provided the basis for an examining ways of choosing the terms of that implicit political agreement. In the middle ages, the prevailing social ideology had precluded the possibility of any departure from existing conventions, but the philosophers of the enlightenment advocated a variety of alternative political systems, some of which have since been adopted. It is now generally accepted that the true test of any political system is whether its advantages justify the sacrifices of individual freedom that it requires.

The concept of the State

Although originally created by governments, "the State" has acquired a notional existence and authority that is independent of the government, the country and the nation with which it is associated. It was identified by the philosopher Max Weber as the only body capable of the legitimate use of force [3]. In its best-known modern form it has the legal characteristics of a corporation in its ability to enter into every form of legal and commercial transaction in the same way as an individual; and it embodies, in each country, a set of rules and conventions termed its constitution that govern the behaviour of its government and the institutions of government; and that can be amended only by its legislature, and usually only by a constitutionally-determined procedure.

Beyond those bare essentials there have been many interpretations of the term and many different attitudes to the concept. For Thomas Hobbes in the 17th century, and for many since then, it has been seen solely as a means of avoiding the chaos of a "war of all against all"[4]. In France after the French revolution, and in some other European countries, the means which it serves came to include the protection of citizens against oppression and, according to the Israeli historian, Martin Van Creveld, it became, for a time, a prized possession "for which they were often prepared to make every sacrifice" including the "rivers of blood" of two world wars[5]. At the other extreme are those who regard the State as the perpetrator of mass murder which it calls war, enslavement that it calls conscription, and robbery that it calls taxation[6].

The best-known category of the state is the stable form that first emerged in modern Europe, but Charles Tilly has described how states have come into existence in a variety of forms and in a variety of circumstances [7], and has shown that stability is not their universal characteristic. The article on failed states contains many examples of former states that have ceased to operate as such, usually following a major erosion of social capital.

Detailed in the article on his book, The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order, Samuel Huntington discusses taxonomies for instability of states and for inter-state conflict.

The rule of law

Ideologies

The functions of ideology

A widely accepted set of beliefs about social behaviour may be termed an ideology if its rationale is known, or a myth if it is not. The term ideology is often associated in people’s minds with dogmatism and intolerance, but in fact, every society has needed a set of shared assumptions to provide it with a settled view about living together. That settled view has typically included conscious beliefs that are topics of everyday discussion, and subconscious attitudes that are seldom examined. It has enabled generally acceptable outcomes to be achieved without debating their underlying rationale. But what group members have considered to be a prized tradition, may have appeared to outsiders to be an irrational ideology.

Social ideologies

Myths about personal status and the nature of authority are part of the foundation of every political ideology. For example, the medieval myth of "the Chain of Being" [8] which defined the hierarchical status of every living thing, was the foundation of feudalism, and its subconscious influence is believed to underlie more recent attitudes to race and gender. And in the nineteenth century, the myth of "the ladder of life" [9] which envisaged evolution as generating a process in which each emerging type of human being is an improvement on its predecessor, was the rationale for a political ideology of the survival of the fittest known as "Social Darwinism" [10]. The formation of groups has led to "we/they" myths about the superiority of members over non-members [11] and the creation of ethnic and nationalist ideologies.

Political ideologies

Several political ideologies have made repeated appearances over the course of history. Authoritarianism, in the form of government by a trained elite, was advocated in the 4th century BCE by Plato [12], and it emerged again in the 20th century as the philosophy of Nazism [13] . Democracy, in the form that gave every citizen a right to participate in every communal decision, made a brief appearance in Pericles’ Athens in the 6th century BCE [14] , but was rejected in that form for centuries thereafter. In particular, the founders of the United States constitution rejected it in favour of "representation ingrafted upon democracy" as advocated in Thomas Paine’s Rights of Man [15]. The concept of representative government, in which the people delegate decision-making powers to an authority on condition that it acts in their interest, had been put forward in the 17th century in the second of John Locke’s treatises On Civil Government [16] and was further developed in the 19th century in John Stuart Mill’s Representative Government [17]. The ideology of Socialism, as the belief that all property should be communally owned, was put forward in the 16th century in Thomas More’s Utopia [18] ; publicised in the early 19th century by Henri de Saint-Simon [19] and developed into an influential creed in Karl Marx’s Das Kapital. [20]. The ideologies of Liberalism and Libertarianism are concerned to preserve individual freedom from state interference. Liberals, such as Friedrich von Hayek [21] , acknowledge the need to impose charges for public goods, whereas some Libertarians such as Robert Nozick are incined to question the need to do so. In opposition to those beliefs, the ideology of Communitarianism that was put forward by Amitai Etzioni [22], lays greater emphasis upon the contribution of community activity to individual welfare.

Theories of government

Legitimacy

The sources of government legitimacy according to the German sociologist Max Weber [23] are charisma, tradition and legality [24] . At a more fundamental level, a government's legitimacy depends upon its continuing ability to perform its side of what is perceived to be the "social contract". Legitimacy once conferred, can be withdrawn for inadequate performance, loss of trust or a change in the public’s interpretation of the contract. In chaotic situations, such as that of Germany at the end WW1, legitimacy can be conferred by a successful undertaking to restore order, but can subsequently be withdrawn if the restoration of order ceases to be considered an adequate recompense for hardship or loss of freedom. Trust can be lost because of what is seen to be misrepresentation, or because of the perceived misappropriation of the community resources by what is termed rent-seeking[25]. Legitimacy is lost by action that is contrary to domestic or international law (although some legal theorists consider international law to be no more than a non-binding system of settling disputes [26]).

Domestic decision-making

Government conduct has been influenced as much by decision-making rationales as by ideologies - there have been tyrannical democracies and benevolent despotisms. It might appear rational for every government decision to be based upon an evaluation of its expected consequences - a rationale that is termed consequentialism - but that rationale is far from being the general rule. Governments have, to varying extents, been influenced by deontism, that is to say by what they perceive to be principles specifying actions that must always to be done or must always be avoided. Some such principles originate from religious codes such as the Ten Commandments or the Moslem Sharia, and some are socially-determined concepts of rights, obligations and duties, such as equity, fair dealing and family responsibilities. Consequentialist acceptance of such principles is conditional upon the absence of significantly harmful consequences, but deontist acceptance is absolute and without exception. The governing principle known as paternalism substitutes the government’s perception of desirable outcomes for that of the governed, either for deontist reasons, or on the ground that the government has the better understanding of the true interests of the governed. At the other extreme is governing behaviour known as populism, under which decisions are influenced by transitory or ill-informed surges of public opinion. Utilitarianism [27] as put forward by John Stuart Mill, treats all of those influences as aberrations, and advocates decision-making that is directed solely at the improvement of the welfare of those affected as they themselves see it. Under that theory, individuals are deemed to delegate to government the responsibility for determining the material consequences of alternative actions, but are themselves deemed to be the sole judge of the resulting social consequences. That theory is in turn rejected in John RawlsA Theory of Justice [28] according to which decisions should conform to the "difference principle" which permits only those inequalities of welfare that benefit the least well-off in the community. Dissenting also from that theory, the philosopher Robert Nozick has argued [29] that each individual has an inalienable right to his own abilities and creations, making it ethically unacceptable for a government to seek to re-allocate the resulting benefits. The assumption that governments govern on behalf of the governed, is in any case challenged by the theory of public choice [30]. That theory assumes that the actions of politicians and civil servants are directed by economic motives, and that they are thus influenced more by self-interest than by a wish to serve the public.

International decision-making

Current forms of government

The various modern forms of government have been categorised in a variety of ways [31] but their most important characteristics concern the accountability of their decision-makers. Accountability is what distinguishes personal- and party-autocracies (such as Saudi Arabia and China) from democracies (such as the United States and the countries of Europe). While it is not impossible for autocracies to perform the functions of representative government, they have little incentive to do so. Whereas the citizens of autocracies can do nothing to influence the conduct of government, the citizens of democracies can exert a degree of influence through their electoral systems.

The existence of constitutional arrangements for the election of representatives does not, however, guarantee accountability (such arrangements exist in Cuba, for example). The reality depends upon the powers and duties of the elected representatives. Parliamentary democracies whose constitutions follow the example of the Westminster system [32] (such as Canada and India) give the elected representatives both legislative powers and the ultimate sanction of the collective ability to dismiss the government, but often leave a government that has a large parliamentary with a substantial degree of autonomy [33].

Countries whose constitutions follow the example of the U.S. Constitution [34] give executive responsibilities to an elected president, and give an elected congress powers to pass laws, and powers of oversight (but not dismissal, except for wrongdoing) over the president.

A number of countries (including France and Italy) have constitutions that combine the parliamentary characteristics of the Westminster model with the presidential features of the United States model. Most countries have written constitutions that can be amended by their electorates and are subject to interpretation by courts such as the Supreme Court of the United States. Such courts are usually appointed rather than elected, but are constitutionally independent of government control. The provision for the democratic participation of the electorate in decision-making is a prominent feature of the constitution of the Swiss cantons, but in most democracies it takes the form of referendums undertaken at the discretion of governments.

Political Institutions

Domestic institutions

It has been established from American experience that policy outcomes are influenced by institutional arrangements such as electoral procedures and conditions of tenure [35], but the major policy impact has everywhere been achieved by the multitude of organisations devoted to influencing government policy by collective action. Groups of people who have beliefs, ideologies or financial interests in common have exerted influence that has often been out of proportion to their numerical strength. (In 1965 the economist Mancur Olson stimulated interest in such organisations by a book [36] in which he stressed the limited incentive for a member to pull his weight in a large group, and concluded that small groups are easier to organise. The subject has since been extensively explored by sociologists and others. [37] ). Interest groups representing specific interests can contribute to the effectiveness of government by supplying it with specialised knowledge, but their main purpose is what has been termed rent-seeking [38], or seeking a sectional advantage at the expense of the rest of the community. The success in that respect of any particular pressure group has been shown to depend upon the activities of competing groups [39]. Farming lobbies have been the most successful of the industrial pressure groups in most developed countries [40] , and, probably next in importance have been the environmental pressure groups such as Greenpeace and Friends of the Earth [41]. The major political pressure groups have of course been the political parties [42] and different party systems have emerged in different countries [43]. Their basic characteristics were explored in the 1960s by the French political scientist Maurice Duverger [44] whose major finding, known as Duverger’s Law [45], was that a first-past-the-post or "plurality electoral system" tends to favour two-party political systems, whereas proportional representation systems tend to favour multi-party politics. Differing forms of proportional representation have been adopted by the major European countries except France and Britain and has normally given rise to multi-party systems and coalition governments, whereas pluralist voting and two-party systems have been the general rule in the United States, Canada, Britain and Australia. There are single-party governments in China, Cuba and Syria and politics have from time to time been dominated by one of a number of parties in Mexico, Japan, Russia and India.

International Institutions

Changes to international relations during the twentieth century have embodied a recognition of growing interdependence. Clusters of local alliances have given way to the concept of extensive mutual defence, there has been a gradual erosion of the concept of the sovereignty of nation states, and there has been increased concern about humanitarian issues. Those trends were reflected in the 1945 charter of the United Nations [46] which proposed world-wide mutual defence, an international court for settling disputes, the protection of refugees, and the prevention and punishment of genocide. Member states have not implemented the original intention to create a military back up for those measures, except on a selective ad hoc basis, and in other respects, the intentions behind the charter have been only partially realised. The constitution of the International Court of Justice [47] does not make it compulsory to accede to a request for the submission of disputes, and the rulings of the court are not binding. The United Nations has had limited success in attempts to prevent any of the 17 subsequent genocides [48] and it was not until 2002 that a court [49] was set up to enable those responsible to be prosecuted. The constitution of the United Nations initially prohibited all intervention in states' domestic affairs, but a commission set up by its Secretary General has since recommended that where a population is suffering serious harm, the principle of non-intervention should give way to "the responsibility to protect" [50] The principle international economic institutions are the World Trade Organisation [51] which develops and regulates agreements concerning trade barriers, the International Monetary Fund [52] which is concerned to maintain exchange stability, and provides temporary financial assistance to countries to help ease balance of payments adjustment, and the World Bank[53] which provides financial and technical assistance to developing countries. The North Atlantic Treaty Organisation (NATO)[54] is a mutual defence institution involving 26 countries in North America and Europe. There are also a number of regional institutions that promote various forms of cooperation, including Free Trade Area of the Americas [55], the Association of South East Asian Nations (ASEAN) [56], the Organisation of African Unity [57], and the European Union [58] , part of which is also a common currency area.

Political Conduct

There are important aspects of politics that are not determined by ideology or institutions. They include campaigning techniques and legislative conduct.

Campaigning

The subject of political tactics was extensively examined by Jeremy Bentham in the nineteenth century [59] and the subject was systematically developed by Anthony Downs in his 1957 book An Economic Theory of Democracy. [60]. The best-known of his conclusions was his median voter theory which claimed that the winning party in a two-party election would be the party that positioned itself the closer to the views of the median voter. The subject has since been widely explored, and the political analyst Jennifer Lees-Marchment has used marketing theory to identify three campaigning strategies: [61]

  • product-oriented strategy concentrating on devising effective policies,
  • sales-oriented strategy focused on publicising the merits of existing policies
  • market-oriented strategy seeking to find out what the public wants and to adjust policies accordingly

The use of marketing professionals for political purposes, which is believed to have originated in the 1960 Kennedy-Nixon Presidential contest, had spread to Britain and elsewhere by the 1970s [62] [63]. Much use was made of focus groups and citizens juries [64] to assess popular reactions to policy proposals, but mainly among uncommitted groups and in marginal constituencies. Considerable efforts were put into influencing public opinion by speeches, and television appearances and mainly by news management or "spin". News management techniques described by Professor Ivor Gabor [65] include rebuttal of opponents’ criticisms, building-up and undermining personalities, kite-flying to gauge public reactions to rumoured proposals, and the timing of announcements to divert attention from bad news. However, adverse public reactions to spin may have since placed some constraint upon the use of such techniques.

Governmental conduct

Legislative conduct has been shown to be strongly influenced by institutional arrangements [66], and party unity is more important in parliamentary systems, which give parliaments the power to dismiss governments, than in presidential systems in which the president retains office for a fixed term. Where party unity is important, party members are often put under pressure by party whips to support declared policies, and party attitudes to new proposals are commonly settled behind closed doors in meetings of the party caucus . Where party unity is less strong, legislative debating is more open, but logrolling [67] conspiracies to gain local advantages are more common.

Current controversies

References

  1. Isaiah Berlin Four Essays on Liberty
  2. Jean-Jacques Rousseau The Social Contract
  3. Max Weber: Politics as a Vocation, in The Vocation Lectures, Hackett, 2004
  4. Thomas Hobbes: The Leviathan, (first published 1660), Oregon State University Library, 2009
  5. Martin Van Creveld: The Rise and Decline of the State, page 334, Cambridge University Press, 2004[1](Questia subscribers)
  6. Murray N. Rothbard: For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto, page 23, Collier Books and the Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2002
  7. Charles Tilly: Coercion, Capital, and European States: AD 990-1990, Blackwell, 1992 {reviewed by Christopher Johnson in Journal of Social History, Fall 1995[2]
  8. Alexander Pope Essay on Man
  9. see Evolution of Species by Michael Lahanas
  10. Social Darwinism
  11. see The Robbers Cave Experiment
  12. Plato The Republic
  13. Adolf Hitler Mein Kampf
  14. Thucidides: Pericles’ Funeral Oration
  15. Thomas Paine The Rights of Man
  16. John Locke On Civil Government
  17. John Stuart Mill Representative Government
  18. Thomas More Utopia
  19. Henri de Saint-Simon
  20. Karl Marx Das Kapital
  21. see Friedrich von Hayek’s Road to Serfdom
  22. Amitai Etzioni's website
  23. Max Weber
  24. Max Weber Economy and Society Bedminster Press, 1968,
  25. Gordon Tullock The Fundamentals of Rent Seeking
  26. Goldsmith and Posner The Limits of International Law Oxford University Press 2005
  27. John Stuart Mill Utilitarianism
  28. John Rawls A Theory of Justice Harvard University Press 1971
  29. Robert Nozick Anarchy, State and Utopia Basic Books 1974
  30. James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock The Calculus of Consent. University of Michigan Press 1962
  31. Systems of Government (Historical Atlas of the Twentieth Century)
  32. Walter Bagehot The English Constitution Kegan Paul 1904
  33. WT Stanbury Accountability to Citizens in the Westminster Model of Government Fraser Institute 2003
  34. The Constitution of the United States of America
  35. Timothy Besley and Anne Case Political Institutions and Policy Choices: Evidence from the United States Institute of Fiscal Studies 1962
  36. Mancur Olson The Logic of Collective Action : Public Goods and the Theory of Groups Harvard University Press 1965
  37. Pamela E. Oliver Formal Models of Collective Action Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 19, 1993
  38. EC Pasour Rent Seeking; Some Conceptual Problems and Implications
  39. Gary S. Becker A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence The Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1983
  40. Agricultural Policy (Cambridge University Model United Nations Society)
  41. Organisations Concerned with Environmental Issues
  42. Alan Ware Political Parties and Party Systems Oxford University Press 1996
  43. Parties around the world
  44. Maurice Duverger Political Parties , Their Organisation and Activity in the Modern State Wiley 1965
  45. Maurice Duverger: Factors in a Two-Party and Multi-party System in Party Politics and Pressure Groups Thomas Y. Crowell, 1972
  46. The United Nations Charter
  47. International Court of Justice
  48. see Jared Diamond The Rise and Fall of the Third Chimpanzee (p258) Vintage 1991
  49. The International Criminal Court
  50. Responsibility to Protect Report of the International Commission on Intervention and State Sovereignty
  51. World Trade Organisation
  52. International Monetary Fund
  53. World Bank
  54. North Atlantic Treaty Organisation
  55. Free Trade Area of the Americas
  56. Association of South East Asian Nations
  57. Organisation of African Unity
  58. European Union
  59. Jeremy Bentham An Essay on Political Tactics in The Works of Jeremy Bentham Bowring 1838
  60. Anthony Downs An Economic Theory of Democracy Harper 1957
  61. Jennifer Lees-Marchment The Marriage of Politics and Marketing Political Studies vol 49 p692 2001
  62. Margaret Scammell Political Marketing: lessons for Political Science Political Studies 1999 p718
  63. Jennifer Lees-Marchment Political Marketing as Party Management National Europe Centre Paper No 110 Australia National University 2003
  64. Tom Wakeford Citizens’ Juries Social Research Update issue 37, University of Sussex 2002
  65. Ivor Gabor Government by Spin Policy Studies Association Conference Papers 1999
  66. John M Carey Political Institutions, Competing Principals and Party Unity in Legislative Voting Institute of Government Studies Working Paper 2005/8 University of California, Berkely 2005
  67. Logrolling (definition)